Market Design's Role in Offshore Energy Growth
Examining how market designs impact offshore wind energy investments.
― 6 min read
Table of Contents
- The Importance of Market Design
- Current Trends in Offshore Energy
- Challenges with Existing Market Designs
- The Proposed Model
- Analyzing Market Designs
- Full Nodal Pricing
- Offshore Nodal Pricing
- Offshore Zonal Pricing
- Full Zonal Pricing
- Implications of Market Designs on Welfare and Profitability
- Impact on Welfare
- Profitability of Offshore Wind Farms
- Conclusions and Recommendations
- Original Source
Offshore electricity markets are becoming more important due to the rise of renewable energy sources, particularly wind power. As governments work on plans to build Offshore Wind Farms, Electrolyzers, and high-voltage direct current (HVDC) transmission systems, it’s essential to figure out the best way to manage these energy resources. A good market design can help in making investments more efficient and in deciding how to distribute electricity.
This article looks at how different market designs affect investments in offshore electrolyzers and transmission capacity. It evaluates two main options: Zonal Pricing and Nodal Pricing. Understanding these pricing methods will help policymakers create better plans for offshore energy infrastructure.
The Importance of Market Design
Market design is how electricity prices are set and how supply and demand are managed. In a zonal pricing system, regions are divided into zones, and a single price is calculated for each zone. In contrast, nodal pricing considers each location (or node) in the network, allowing for unique prices based on local supply and demand.
Zonal pricing is simpler and often used in Europe, where prices align with national borders. In contrast, nodal pricing is more common in the United States, where prices can vary more significantly based on local conditions.
A well-designed market can lead to more efficient resource allocation, meaning that energy can be supplied where it is needed most and at the lowest cost. This is particularly important for offshore energy systems, which need to manage energy not only from wind farms but also from other technologies like storage and electrolyzers.
Current Trends in Offshore Energy
As of 2021, the global capacity for offshore wind power was 56 gigawatts (GW) and is predicted to grow significantly. Besides wind power, technologies like energy storage and electrolyzers are also being developed for use offshore. These systems often connect wind farms through HVDC technology, allowing electricity to be transported over long distances efficiently.
Besides government efforts, electricity prices play a crucial role in guiding investments in these technologies. If prices are set correctly, they can encourage developers to invest where it makes the most sense. However, the current market designs in many regions, such as the EU, may not fully capture the complexities of offshore energy generation and consumption.
Challenges with Existing Market Designs
Many studies on electricity markets place their focus on onshore systems, overlooking offshore systems. This is problematic because offshore energy markets have unique characteristics, such as the presence of HVDC technology. Current studies often make simplifying assumptions that do not accurately reflect the operational realities of offshore energy generation.
For instance, most existing literature does not consider how the market design affects investment decisions. Since pricing methods can impact the profitability of offshore wind farms and the deployment of new technologies, it's vital to evaluate these relationships.
The Proposed Model
This article introduces a new model that considers the dynamics of offshore energy markets more thoroughly. The model assesses how different market designs influence investments in both offshore wind farms and electrolyzers. It also looks at the operational decisions that take place in electricity markets.
The model is structured in several layers. The first layer focuses on the overall goal of maximizing the social welfare of the energy market, which includes the economic benefits derived from the electricity sold, alongside the costs of investments in transmission and electrolyzer capacity.
The subsequent layers are concerned with optimizing the investments in HVDC transmission and electrolyzer capacity while ensuring a proper market clearing process. The model allows for different pricing methods to be tested against each other.
Analyzing Market Designs
In this analysis, there are four key market designs under consideration:
- Full Nodal Pricing (FNP)
- Offshore Nodal Pricing (ONP)
- Offshore Zonal Pricing (OZP)
- Full Zonal Pricing (FZP)
Each of these designs has its own strengths and weaknesses.
Full Nodal Pricing
FNP provides the most accurate price signals because it allows prices to vary by location. This method helps to signal the need for new investments in transmission capacity and encourages optimal resource use. However, it can be more complex to implement and may face political resistance.
Offshore Nodal Pricing
ONP integrates offshore areas into the nodal pricing system. This method improves upon traditional zonal pricing by allowing for unique prices in offshore locations. It is seen as a middle ground that can lead to better investment decisions than simply using zonal pricing.
Offshore Zonal Pricing
OZP divides the offshore areas into zones but keeps a simpler pricing system by setting a single price for each zone. This makes it easier to manage but can result in less efficient outcomes compared to nodal systems.
Full Zonal Pricing
FZP is the most straightforward method. It simplifies the management of the market by using one price for each zone. However, this can lead to inefficiencies, as it may not reflect local supply and demand accurately. In many regions, this is the existing method, but it may not be the best for future offshore developments.
Implications of Market Designs on Welfare and Profitability
The choice of market design has significant implications for the overall welfare of the system, which refers to the total benefits to society from electricity generation and consumption.
Impact on Welfare
The research shows that ONP and OZP generally lead to better welfare outcomes than FZP, despite the latter's simplicity. The more accurate representation of grid constraints in ONP and OZP helps to reduce costs associated with curtailment (when energy is not used) and redispatch (when energy is adjusted post-market clearing).
The results indicate that participants benefit more under ONP and OZP due to lower overall costs, which can lead to a higher surplus from generating and supplying energy.
Profitability of Offshore Wind Farms
One of the critical findings is that the profitability of offshore wind farms is affected by the market design. Under FZP, wind farms often achieve higher profits. However, when using ONP or OZP, profitability may decrease because these designs can lead to lower average prices for electricity.
The research highlights that a lower average price under ONP and OZP can still benefit offshore consumers like electrolyzers. If these consumers invest in offshore energy, they can contribute to higher overall demand, which may improve the profitability of wind farms in the long run.
Conclusions and Recommendations
The analysis shows that FNP is the most beneficial market design for maximizing welfare and profit in offshore systems. However, due to political and practical challenges, many areas still use FZP.
ONP and OZP are promising alternatives that improve welfare while allowing for some market efficiency. They can support the integration of offshore consumers and technologies, which are essential for reducing greenhouse gas emissions and moving towards a renewable energy future.
Policymakers should consider a move toward more nuanced pricing methods for offshore energy systems. This could involve better coordination between market designs and policies supporting offshore technologies, ensuring the development of infrastructure that accommodates the growing offshore energy sector.
In summary, a shift in market design could lead to significant benefits for both energy producers and consumers while supporting wider goals of sustainability and energy security.
Title: Evaluating Offshore Electricity Market Design Considering Endogenous Infrastructure Investments: Zonal or Nodal?
Abstract: Policy makers are formulating offshore energy infrastructure plans, including wind turbines, electrolyzers, and HVDC transmission lines. An effective market design is crucial to guide cost-efficient investments and dispatch decisions. This paper jointly studies the impact of offshore market design choices on the investment in offshore electrolyzers and HVDC transmission capacity. We present a bilevel model that incorporates investments in offshore energy infrastructure, day-ahead market dispatch, and potential redispatch actions near real-time to ensure transmission constraints are respected. Our findings demonstrate that full nodal pricing, i.e., nodal pricing both onshore and offshore, outperforms the onshore zonal combined with offshore nodal pricing or offshore zonal layouts. While combining onshore zonal with offshore nodal pricing can be considered as a second-best option, it generally diminishes the profitability of offshore wind farms. However, if investment costs of offshore electrolyzers are relatively low, they can serve as catalysts to increase the revenues of the offshore wind farms. This study contributes to the understanding of market designs for highly interconnected offshore power systems, offering insights into the impact of congestion pricing methodologies on investment decisions. Besides, it is useful towards understanding the interaction of offshore loads like electrolyzers with financial support mechanisms for offshore wind farms.
Authors: Michiel Kenis, Vladimir Dvorkin, Tim Schittekatte, Kenneth Bruninx, Erik Delarue, Audun Botterud
Last Update: 2024-05-21 00:00:00
Language: English
Source URL: https://arxiv.org/abs/2405.13169
Source PDF: https://arxiv.org/pdf/2405.13169
Licence: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
Changes: This summary was created with assistance from AI and may have inaccuracies. For accurate information, please refer to the original source documents linked here.
Thank you to arxiv for use of its open access interoperability.